Реферат по предмету "Иностранный язык"


China s industrial and foreign trade policies what are they and how successful have they been

China
’s industrial and foreign trade policies:


what are they and how successful have they been?


Introduction


This paper briefly considers two major questions about China’s industrial and foreign economic policies. First, what is the best way to describe China’s economic growth model, particularly as it relates to international trade and investment? And second, how successful has this model been, not only in generating high GDP growth, but in respect of three other criteria:


a) acquisition of technology and development of innovative capacity;


b) development of competitive domestic firms; and


c) acquisition of political power in the international trading system.


The conclusion is that China’s economic growth model shares the goals of a classical East Asian developmental state, but at the policy level is severely constrained by the paradoxical task of dismantling the old communist economic system while maintaining the Communist Party’s absolute monopoly on political power. To the extent that the exigencies of political stability make it difficult to execute economic reform, an unusually high degree of openness to foreign investment and trade is required as a catalyst for economic reform. This model, which differs markedly from those employed by other Asian countries, has been highly successful at generating economic growth and facilitating the import and diffusion of technology. However the relative dearth of domestic innovation and internationally prominent Chinese firms is a persistent source of anxiety for policy makers.


In the last two decades China has claimed its place as a major center of trade andmanufacturing activities in the world. The Chinese economy has demonstratedunprecedented growth through its national policy of reform and opening up to theoutside world following Maoist isolationism and disarray stemming from theCultural Revolution. But while this has led to tremendous social welfare gains inChina and has contributed to global trade in significant ways, Chinese manufacturers have also had to confront its trading partners in the advanced industrialized world over a mounting range of causes of trade friction. For example, not only were Chinese manufacturers and authorities increasingly presented with antidumping suits initiated by China’s major trading partners, they also have had to respond to Washington’s pressure to revalue the Chinese currency, the RMB, and have clashed head to head with the United States over its protective duties on products such as furniture, semiconductors, and automobile parts. The tone and genre of US trade relations with China seem to have harkened back to the height of US– Japan trade relations in the 1980s. It is not an exaggeration to say that China has become one of the main rivals of the United States in the area of trade policy and that China is likely to remain at the center of US trade policy in the years to come. These growing causes of trade friction between China and the US raise important questions both about the sources of these conflicts and the future orientation of US–China trade relations. They also raise questions about the process of trade policymaking in China which, up until now, has remained rather opaque to outside observers. Existing studies of China’s interactions with its major trading partners have examined how China bargained with the US on the basis of the assumption of a unitary actor (e.g. Mertha and Pahre, 2005). They have also treated Chinese foreign trade policy as a case study of the making of Chinese foreign policy in general or focused on the implications of China’s accession into the World Trade Organization (WTO) for the Chinese economy and society. Relatively little scholarly attention has been devoted to the domestic politics behind China’s behavior in the world trading system.1 This question is nevertheless of vital importance as it directly bears on the future of China’s role in regional and global trade relations. It is therefore important to address this lacuna in order to understand how China does and will continue to respond to trade challenges from abroad. This volume represents a collective effort to unpack the domestic politics of trade policymaking in China and tackles questions about the emerging forces shaping China’s foreign trade policy. Its emphasis on how domestic actors shape China’s behavior in the international trade realm promises to offer a novel perspective on China’s international economic relations. Specifically, this project addresses the following questions:


• What is the domestic political process of trade policymaking in China? Is it


changing? If so, in what ways?


• What kind of formal institutional changes have been necessary for a formerly


centrally planned economy such as that of China to make such a transition?


• What is the changing pattern of trade policy lobbying in China?


• How did institutional reforms such as decentralization and administrative


reorganization affect China’s trade policymaking process and outcomes?


• To what extent does domestic politics in China influence the outcome of


China’s bilateral disputes and China’s activities in the rules-based international trading system? While the processes and changes described in this book are still tentative and ongoing, they nevertheless capture major dimensions of the making of trade policy zin China and provide us with a first cut into this important issue.


Description of the model


China’s economic development model, while combining elements of other models, is a unique amalgam reflecting various peculiarities of Chinese state and society. It also depends to a significant degree on China’s sheer size, which makes it virtually unique – India being the only country in the world with anywhere near the same population and hence potential market size. Comparisons with the experiences of other countries are thus of limited value. To describe the Chinese model, we will look at it from three angles: the post-communist emerging market, the East Asian developmental state; and the free-market liberal state. Although China conforms to none of these ideal types, it embraces important elements of each.


Post-communist emerging market.
Beginning in 1978, China gradually abandoned most elements of the Soviet-style planned economy it had set up in the 1950s and 1960s. A key difference between this reform effort and those of eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union in the years after 1989 was that in China the Communist Party succeeded in maintaining its grip on political power, and this grip remains undiminished to this day. Thus China is an almost unique example of a post- communist economy with continuing Communist Party government (Vietnam is the other instance).


The most significant effect of this difference between China and other post-communist economies came in privatization of state-owned enterprises. Instead of the varieties of mass privatization executed in eastern Europe and many of the states of the former Soviet Union, China deliberately avoided privatization and focused on deregulating prices and creating competitive markets. There was no large scale privatization effort until after the 1997-98 Asian financial crisis; and even then this privatization focused on smaller enterprises while leaving the main, centrally-controlled state enterprises untouched. Almost a decade later, the state sector still controls around 40 percent of business-sector output2 and state firms dominate many key industries, including aviation, shipping, steel, oil, chemicals, telecoms, coal, metals and power generation. China has a huge number of private companies but they are mostly tiny; there no large private business groups able to exercise political influence at the national level. Meanwhile the party-state, which has shown a surprising degree of resilience, has done an impressive job of restructuring and rationalizing the largest state enterprises, evidently with the view of keeping these business groups firmly in state hands, but at greatly increased levels of profitability and global competitiveness. 3


One of the biggest unknowns of China’s future development path is how the relationship among the party-state, the top-tier state enterprises, and the rapidly growing private sector will play out. Although there is significant debate on this subject, it seems clear that at present the party-state has no intention of divesting itself of the 150 or so largest state enterprise groups.4 Thus the central government intends to continue exercising control over substantial elements of the national economy through direct ownership of operating companies. Meanwhile, private-sector companies will increasingly be encouraged, as they are the principal engine of job-creation, as well as the main mechanism for meeting demand in consumer markets.


This raises the question of what occurs when the interests of the entrenched state sector and the up-and-coming private sector conflict. Up to now, such conflicts have been minimal. This is partly because policy has roughly divided the economy into sectors where state dominance is presumed and barriers to private-sector players are high, and other sectors where competition is virtually unrestricted. State enterprises can survive in these latter sectors but only by competing on more or less equal terms with their private competitors.5 This policy in effect creates separate spheres of operation for private firms and “strategic” state enterprises.


A second strategy is co-optation of private entrepreneurs, either through financial mechanisms or by membership in the Communist party. An example of the former is telecommunications firm Huawei, which in 2004 received a concessional Rmb10 billion (US$1.2 billion) line of credit from the China Development Bank, a state policy-lending institution. Co-optation via Communist party membership, long an informal practice, was re-instituted on a formal basis in 2002 when a 13-year-old ban on inducting entrepreneurs was eliminated from the Party constitution.6


These methods serve present political purposes fairly well. One consequence, however, is that the state has a fairly clear interest in discouraging the emergence of the large family conglomerates that are characteristic of Chinese commercial culture everywhere else in Asia.7 This poses a potential problem for the future. What happens when these sorts of conglomerates start to grow, as they must, out of the small-scale private business groups that exist today? Do the new tycoons begin to insist on an autonomous political role free of Party interference? Can a new accommodation be reached? Or will the state insist on restricting or dismantling these groups as they become too big, with a resulting cost in economic efficiency?


2. East Asian developmental state.
In broad terms, China clearly shares certain key characteristics with Japan in the 1950s and 60s, and with South Korea in the 1970s onwards. Economic growth is driven by a high savings rate, large state investments in infrastructure, rapid transfer of population from agricultural to manufacturing employment, and export-oriented industries.


A key difference, however, is that the effective level of protection for domestic enterprises in most sectors is far lower in China than in its east Asian neighbors, and the participation of foreign companies in both the domestic market and in export trade is much higher. As will be seen below, this has important implications for China’s technological development path. It also means that China has not yet developed what might be called the “clientelist” type of capitalism, different varieties of which prevail in many Asian economies. In Japan, clientelism took the form of cartels orchestrated by the government, which kept domestic prices high and ensured fat corporate profit margins. In southeast Asia, the standard form was the granting of monopoly concessions for key commodities to favored entrepreneurs, who used the cash flow thus derived to build up diversified family-controlled conglomerates. In China, as noted above, the main mechanisms of accommodation between state and private sector have been the creation of separate spheres of activity, and ad hoc
forms of co-optation. Because of the highly competitive nature of most markets, cartels are ineffective, and commodity extraction is seen as inherently a state activity. The main consequence is that China has not so far fostered either internationally competitive and technologically advanced multinational firms (as in Japan or Korea), or internationally prominent family-run conglomerates (as in southeast Asia).


Figure 1



3. Liberal free-market state.
Because of its extraordinary degree of openness, it is tempting to imagine that China is headed toward some version of a liberal, free-market state. And it is true that in downstream manufacturing industries from which state players have exited, China is characterized by an astonishing degree of competition, which in many cases includes not only dozens or hundreds of Chinese companies but also the major players from virtually every other country in the world.


This state of affairs results from the fact that Chinese economic reform, since its inception in 1978, has been explicitly a process not only of domestic reform (gaige
) but also of opening-up to the global economy (kaifang
). The relentless ubiquity of the phrase gaige kaifang
in official parlance over the past quarter-century has perhaps dulled the understanding of the momentousness of this word choice. The clear implication is that domestic reform is impossible without openness; and because the phrase was enunciated by Deng Xiaoping himself it is politically impossible to jettison it. Reformers have used openness as a tools to spur domestic reforms that otherwise would have been far more difficult or even impossible, most notably via China’s accession to the WTO in December 2001.


China’s degree of openness is illustrated first by Figure 1, which shows exports, imports and total trade as a percentage of GDP. These figures are quite high for a large economy: China’s total trade ratio, 64 percent of GDP, is about triple that of Japan or the United States (although similar to Germany’s). Notably, growth in both imports and exports rose steeply right after WTO accession. In the four years since, trade has grown at more than double the rate of nominal GDP, whereas in the preceding eight years trade and GDP grew at about the same rate on average.


Figure 2


Foreign enterprise share of China’s export and trade balance




Unique to China among large trading nations is the enormous share of exports and the trade balance accounted for by foreign invested enterprises (FIEs), as shown in Figure 2. At 58 percent and 55 percent respectively in 2005, these figures are without doubt far and away the highest for any major economy, although definitional differences make direct comparisons hard. Moreover, the foreign share of both has risen steadily.


The major risk of the openness strategy, from the Chinese point of view, is that China’s economy could wind up being “Latin Americanized,” with many market sectors controlled by foreign firms. In his study of the Chinese auto sector, Eric Thun notes that efforts to create an internationally competitive Chinese automaker have


thus far fared poorly, and suggests that the Chinese auto industry does indeed face some risk of repeating the fate of Mexico’s, which – in part because of the market-


opening North American Free Trade Agreement – is entirely controlled at both the assembly and the component level by multinational firms.9


Although fear of domination by foreign multinationals remains a potent political force – even if one which, in the end, is usually trumped by the forces of openness – it is unlikely that large swathes of Chinese industry will end up being dominated by foreigners. The main reason is the sheer size of the country. The lure of this potential market enables China to impose significant entry fees on multinationals, such as technology transfer, mandatory joint ventures, or limitations of business scope. In one way or another these barriers provide breathing space for Chinese competitors.


Perhaps the best way concisely to sum up the Chinese development model is as a symbiosis of the three types indicated above. The goals
of Chinese development are patterned on the classic East Asian developmental states, Japan and South Korea: China’s leaders would like to see rapid economic growth, heavily reliant on exports and rapid technological advance, with a stable administration of elite technocrats playing a substantial coordinating role.10 However the methods
for achieving these goals are dictated by China’s peculiar status as a post-communist economy with a continuing Communist government
. Unlike South Korea and Japan, China must gradually dismantle the constricting apparatus of the planned economy. This process of dismantling, however, must not threaten the rule of the Communist Party itself, and carries the additional condition that the party-state must remain in direct control of large chunks of the economy through ownership of dominant enterprises in strategic sectors. Left to the mercy of purely domestic forces, such a complicated and contradictory reform process would most likely run aground. Thus a high degree of market openness is essential as a catalyst
, to ensure that structural reforms continue without which economic development and technological advance are impossible.


It is important to recognize that technocratic governance exists in China mainly as an ideal. The practical reality of Chinese policymaking is fragmented and politically constrained, with most policies emerging as compromises between semi-autonomous central government ministries, or as the result of tortuous negotiations between the center and local governments, over which Beijing has at best imperfect control.


Measuring success


Having defined as best we can the nature of the Chinese economic development model, we can now make a brief survey of how successful the model has been. In terms of economic growth the question is easy to answer. Between 1980 and 2005 China’s GDP grew by an annual average rate of 9.6 percent. No other country (including Japan, South Korea and Taiwan) has ever sustained that rate of GDP growth for such a long period of time. It is not within the scope of this paper to disentangle the various contributions of policy, demographics, and other factors to growth; it is sufficient to suggest that in the context of such spectacular growth, it is inconceivable that policy played a negative role, and it is probable that it played a strongly positive one.


Impact on technology and development of competitive domestic firms


But as we have noted, it is not the goal of Chinese policy to create economic growth pure and simple. Other policy goals include the creation of domestic technology capacity, and the development of internationally competitive Chinese firms. On both of these counts China’s success is ambiguous.


To understand this it is necessary to go back to China’s trade figures. Between 1980 and 2005 China leapt from being a negligible trader to the world’s third biggest trading nation, behind only the US and Germany. This was accomplished in large measure by policies designed to attract export-oriented foreign direct investment. These policies were enormously successful; as noted above foreign enterprises accounted for well over half of China’s exports in 2005, and the foreign share has been rising. Moreover, as shown by Figure 2, the foreign contribution to China’s trade surplus, quite modest in the 1990s, became dominant in recent years. The most likely explanation is that foreign enterprises were heavy importers of capital equipment in the 1990s, as they were installing their factories. While these imports continue, they are now outweighed by the production value of exports from the installed base.


Two additional points need to be made. First, the role of processing trade. More than half of China’s trade is processing – i.e., final assembly of imported materials and components. Processing’s share of total trade has not declined appreciably in recent years, nor has the local value-added component of processing increased significantly (see Figure 3). Chinese trade growth, and by extension overall economic performance, are quite reliant on this relatively low value-added processing trade


Figure 3


China
’s processing trade




Source: Ministry of Commerce


.


When one turns to goods classified as high-tech, the picture is even more stark. In 2005, 88 percent of China’s high-tech exports were generated by foreign firms – and 67 percent by wholly owned foreign firms, in which there is no formal mechanism for technology transfer to a local partner. FIEs are now significant net exporters of technology goods, while domestic firms continue to be net importers (see Figure 4). On a more qualitative basis, there is little evidence that Chinese firms are producing significant innovation in core technologies, manufacturing process, or design – either in high tech goods or in any other sector. The primary Chinese comparative advantage continues to be production at low cost and on a large scale. Chinese companies that have demonstrated international competitiveness, for instance steel producer Baosteel, telecoms equipment maker Huawei, and auto components maker Wanxiang, have done so not on the basis of new technology or innovative manufacturing process, but mainly by their ability to manufacture to an acceptable standard at very low cost. There are a large number of such companies, mainly small and medium sized manufacturers.


Figure 4


China
high-tech merchandise trade, 2002 and 2005



Source: Ministry of Commerce


Figure 5


Trade balance composition, 1990-2005



From an economic point of view there is nothing terribly wrong with this. Because of its unique cost and scale advantages, China will be able to generate enormous increases in employment and incomes simply by commoditizing an ever wider range of technologies invented elsewhere. As Figure 5 demonstrates, this widening of China’s industrial base – represented by China’s trade balance in five major goods categories – is proceeding rapidly. In 2005 China was a large net exporter of machinery (to the tune of US$60 billion) and industrial intermediates (US$45 billion), both categories in which as recently as three years earlier it was a net importer. In the long run, these large concentrations of manufacturing capacity, and the development of a richer and more demanding domestic consumer market, are bound to prompt domestic technological innovation.


Yet from the point of view of Chinese planners who define success in terms of maximizing “comprehensive national power” and would like to create local versions of Toyota and Sony, the picture is distressing. When Chinese planners talk of “internationally competitive” they do not simply mean companies that can compete effectively in international markets, which as we have noted many Chinese firms are already able to do. Rather, they mean companies that have globally recognized brand names; intellectual property rights from which they can reap price premiums, royalties and license fees; and control of distribution channels in foreign markets. In other words, Chinese planners explicitly reject the Taiwanese model of small, nimble manufacturing firms that operate mainly on a contract basis with the owners of brands and distribution channels in developed-country markets. Instead they favor the creation of Japanese-style multinational firms.


Common themes of government pronouncements now is the undesirability of China remaining “locked into low-value assembly production,” and the desirability of developing indigenous intellectual property so that Chinese firms can collect rather than pay royalties and license fees. This concern has spawned a number of strategies, including incentive packages for technology industries, the promotion of domestic technology standards, and government procurement rules mandating purchase of domestic hardware and software. The most prominent example of the first was State Council Document 18, published in 2000, which provided a wide range of tax and other benefits for domestic producers of semiconductors and software. These were attacked by US semiconductor makers as an illegal subsidy and were rescinded in April 2005.


The problem with these sorts of policy measures is that by constantly trying to create explicit or implicit discrimination between foreign-owned and domestic enterprises, the government converts what ought to be industrial policy into a trade issue. The two things most required for domestic innovation to flourish and for Chinese multinationals to grow are a) an improvement in the rewards system for innovation (including improved intellectual property protection and more flexible capital markets) and b) and consolidation of industry so that the most efficient players can focus on research and development and well thought-out international expansion, rather than fighting vicious price wars at home in order to maintain market share.


A final consideration is to what extent China’s growth has enabled it to gain power in the international trading system. To the extent that it is now the world’s third largest trading nation, China obviously wields influence over the trade policies of many of its partners. Yet as a new entrant into the WTO it does not as yet gained a significant role in setting the rules of international trade; and insofar as it is perceived as a heel-dragger in meeting its WTO obligations, its impact on further adjustments in the WTO regime is likely to be limited, except in a negative sense (i.e. blocking WTO rules on matters that Beijing sees as helpful protectionist tools, such as government procurement policies). This relatively low level of influence does not yet seem to be an issue of great concern in Beijing, where policy makers are far more engrossed in domestic reform issues than they are in securing a favorable operating environment for Chinese firms abroad. China’s interest in taking a more active role in WTO rule-setting will presumably grow in tandem with the presence of Chinese multinationals in international markets. It is likely, however, that such international concerns will continue to take a back seat to domestic considerations for many years to come.


Hard-won achievements of China's foreign economic and trade cooperation in 1998.


The aggregate trade value basically reached the same level of the previous year with continued growth of our export. According to the Custom's statistics, national import and export value totaled 323.93 billion US dollars, down 0.4%. In a breakdown, export stood at 183.76 billion US dollars, up 0.5%; import amounted to 140.17 billion, down 1.5%. Trade surplus in the whole year accumulated to 43.59 billion US dollars, increasing by 7.9%. The commodity structure of our imports and exports further improved as the export value of mechanical and electronic products increased by 12.2% to 66.54 billion US dollars, taking up a larger percentage of 36.2% in total export.


The newly-signed contractual foreign investment realized recovery growth and the actually paid-in capital maintained to grow. Last year, the number of newly approved foreign-invested enterprises nationwide was 19846, down 5.7% from the previous year; the newly-signed contractual foreign investment witnessed a growth of 2.21% and a total of 52.132 billion US dollars, realizing growth rebound after decline by large margin for two years in a row in 1996 and 1997. And the actually utilized foreign capital grew up by 0.67% to 45.582 billion US dollars. Features of utilizing foreign investment in 1998 could be summed up as follows: foreign investment in China sourcing from Europe, America and some free ports made headway continuously; the industrial structure of foreign investment further improved; the average amount of utilized foreign capital for a project increased to some extent; and the mid-western part of China increased the attraction of foreign investment by an obviously larger scale when compared to the eastern region. By the end of 1998, China has accumulatively approved over 320,000 foreign-invested enterprises with 572.5 billion US dollars of contractual foreign capital and 267.45 billion of paid-in foreign capital.


Foreign project-contracting and labor services cooperation have made relatively large progress. The newly-signed contractual volume of foreign project-contracting, labor service cooperation and designing consultation involves 11.77 billion US dollars, moving up 3.7%. The accomplished turnover reached 10.13 billion US dollars, up 20.9%. At the end of the year, over 350,000 Chinese were providing labor services abroad.


Foreign assistance further progressed with the reform of its modalities advancing steadily. China signed agreements on financial assistance with a number of countries last year. Substantive progress has been made in foreign assistance and reform on its modalities.


Overseas investment witnessed initial development. By the end of 1998, enterprises investing abroad who had been approved by or registered at MOFTEC totalled 5,666 with an overall contractual Chinese capital of 6.33 billion US dollars.


Reform on the administration system of foreign trade and economic cooperation made active progress. We further opened up the right to import and export. For the 1,000 State-owned Enterprises with which the State emphatically contacted, we enforced the system of registration for record on the foreign trade right and extended the coverage of this system to more than 6,800 large-scale industrial enterprises nationwide as of January this year. We promulgated the Interim Regulations on Endowing the Right to Import and Export to Private Manufacturing Enterprises and Scientific Research Institutes which had been approved by the State Council. The Regulations came into official enforcement as of January 1, 1999 and 20 private manufacturing enterprises have obtained the right to trade as the first group pursuant to the approval. We also relaxed the approving criteria for provincial and municipal trading companies to establish subsidiaries in Pudong New District of Shanghai. And we have scored new achievements in restructuring export commodities management system.


Multilateral and bilateral economic and trade relations kept developing. China strengthened its negotiations with US and other WTO members, actively participated in the activities of Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation and played an important role in it. China frequently exchanged high-profile visits with the United States, European Union, Russia and Japan, which have laid solid foundation for bilateral economic and trade ties and pushed forward bilateral collaboration in these aspects. Due to the adverse impact of Asian Financial Crisis, our export to Asia plummeted last year. Meanwhile, our export to other regions increased to varied extent. To be more specific, our export to US was 37.98 billion US dollars, up 16.1%; export value to Europe was 28.15 billion US dollars, up 18.1%; to Africa, 4.06 billion US dollars, up 26.5%; and to Latin America, 5.32 billion with 15.5% of increment. The economic and trade relations between mainland and Hong Kong became even closer. Our economic and trade ties with Macao also developed smoothly which has created favorable conditions for the successful reunification of Macao this year. And the economic and trade relations between the mainland and Taiwan continued developing.


All the achievements were made under the circumstances of deepening impact of Asian Financial Crisis, severe economic recessions, drastic devaluation and general declines of imports and exports in many neighboring countries, and against the backdrop of serious flooding within China and non-devaluation of Chinese Renminbi. The achievements are therefore by no means easy. Such achievements of China's foreign trade and economy sector under those difficult circumstances should be attributed to: first, the great importance the Central Party Committee and the State Council have attached to the cause of foreign trade and economic cooperation and their timely, correct policies; second, the strong supports and active cooperation from all localities and departments; third, the precious spirit of hard struggle as demonstrated by people of all sectors involved in foreign trade and economic cooperation.


Of course, while posing difficulties for the development of China's foreign trade and economic affairs, the Asian financial Crisis has hardened the adaptability of our foreign trade enterprises and heightened the urgency of strengthening the two fundamental transformations and risk prevention.


The situation and major tasks for the development of foreign trade and economic cooperation of China this year.


The situation faced by China's foreign trade and economic sector this year could be even harder and more complicated. The situation remains harsh. The impact of Asian financial crisis is deepening, and the world is entering a period of adjustment with weakening growth momentum. International demands are sliding drastically. Trade protectionism is gaining ground, resulting in heightened trade frictions. Besides, the scientific and technological advantages of developed nations and the price comparative advantages of certain Southeastern Asian nations due to devaluation of their currencies could become even more prominent factors. With the slowdown of the aggregate growth of global transnational direct investments, the inflows of international capital into the developing nations this year may continue to decline; The crisis-stricken countries are formulating one after another more favorable policies to lure foreign investment and this could have a negative impact on China's absorption of foreign investment.


At the ongoing national conference on foreign trade and economic cooperation in Beijing, Minister Shi Guangsheng pointed out that this year our work faces a harsh situation, but we still possess quite a number of favorable conditions. Internationally speaking, the general environment and China's relations with its major trade partners remain fine, and the world economy and trade sustains growth. Since China accounts for a low share of world trade, there is still potential for growth. Internally, first, the sustained high speed healthy growth of our national economy provides a forceful material guarantee and institutional condition for the development of foreign trade and economy; second, the pattern of diversified operators of foreign trade and economy has taken initial shape, which represents an unprecedented incentive to all types of foreign trade and economic enterprises; third, the State has introduced and is working on more policies and measures to expand exports and attract foreign investment, such as the significant move of further raising tax rebate rates for exports in accordance with international practice; fourth, our country enjoys political and monetary stability, and our market has a huge potential, and it is still a fairly attractive investment site.


The major tasks of China's foreign trade and economic cooperation this year are: to strive to expand exports and try to achieve growth of certain extent, and to appropriately increase imports; to utilize more foreign investments in a better way, and maintain the sizeable scale of foreign investment, raising the quality and level of foreign capital utilization; work hard to develop overseas project contracting and labor cooperation; to actively promote the reform of foreign aid; to do a good job in bilateral and multilateral trade and economic relations so as to create international environment for the development of foreign trade and economic relations; to fully fulfill the various tasks of foreign trade and economic relations in order to contribute to the sustained high-speed healthy development of the national economy.


Comprehensively implement the spirit of the Central Economic Work Meeting and properly handle the relationship between expanding domestic demand and developing foreign trade and economic cooperation.


This year, the Central Government has determined that China will pursue its active fiscal policies to enhance domestic demand so that stable economic growth could be maintained. This is a very correct decision, the implementation of which will contribute to the lessening of negative impact imposed on China's economy by the Asian financial crisis, and to the adjustment of China's economic structure and its long-term development. However, stressing the expansion of domestic demand doesn't mean that foreign economic and trade cooperation is insignificant. We will consistently adhere to the fundamental state policy of opening-up, which is proved to be a piece of successful experience of China's rapid economic development since the Third Plenary Session of the Eleventh Central Committee of the Communist Party of China. Economic development should rely on both domestic and foreign markets. We should give full consideration of the difficulties China might meet in this year's export, yet that could never be paraphrased as neglecting or even abandoning foreign market. Instead, we shall leave no stone unturned in expanding export.


Foreign economic and trade cooperation enjoys a vital position in China's national economy, next only to active fiscal policy. Foreign economic and trade development will be conducive to the promotion of speedy national economic growth. Export occupies considerable proportion of China's GDP and foreign investment absorption also makes a certain ratio of the social fixed assets investment. Therefore, the maintenance of stable growth in export and foreign investment utilization will surly help realize the expected growth target of the national economy.


Foreign economic and trade development will contribute to the restructuring and upgrading of China's industry. Through utilizing foreign investment, enlarging export and encouraging overseas investment of Chinese enterprises with comparative advantages, China will be in a better position to optimize its industrial structure and raise the products' competitiveness in international market.


Foreign economic and trade development is also beneficial to balance international payment and to stabilize the exchange rate of Chinese currency, which can bring about a favorable external environment for the expansion of domestic demand.


Foreign economic and trade development will be incremental to sustain and increase employment, and to maintain basic stability of domestic demand as well as social stability.



Не сдавайте скачаную работу преподавателю!
Данный реферат Вы можете использовать для подготовки курсовых проектов.

Поделись с друзьями, за репост + 100 мильонов к студенческой карме :

Пишем реферат самостоятельно:
! Как писать рефераты
Практические рекомендации по написанию студенческих рефератов.
! План реферата Краткий список разделов, отражающий структура и порядок работы над будующим рефератом.
! Введение реферата Вводная часть работы, в которой отражается цель и обозначается список задач.
! Заключение реферата В заключении подводятся итоги, описывается была ли достигнута поставленная цель, каковы результаты.
! Оформление рефератов Методические рекомендации по грамотному оформлению работы по ГОСТ.

Читайте также:
Виды рефератов Какими бывают рефераты по своему назначению и структуре.