Реферат по предмету "Английский язык"


International Raw Materials Market

International Raw Materials Market

by A.E 
Epechourin, group 1078/2

St-Petersburg State Technical University

The Department of Economic & Management

The Chair of World Economics 

St-Petersburg

1997
Introduction

Raw Materials - A natural of semifinished god that is
used in manufacturing or processing to make some other good. Bauxite is the raw
materials (ore) from which aluminum is made; aluminum is turn can be the raw
material from which household utensils are manufactured.[1]

There is another definitions from the subject area of
raw materials  distinct from the above
mentioned:   

 Raw materials
are products immediately extracted from nature which have undergone a first
processing through which they have become marketable and, consequently, a
tradable commodity. Raw materials include all energy raw materials (crude oil,
natural gas, coal, uranium), metals, semi-metals and industrial minerals (kaolin,
graphite, sulfur, salts, phosphates), rocks, water as well as all plant and
animal products, whether they come from tropical regions (coffee, jute,
tropical timber) or from temperate latitudes (wheat, meat, wool, etc.).[2]

 Raw material
economy: It comprises all activities which are part of the planned handling of
raw materials, i.e. explanation, evaluation, extraction, conversion into a
tradable product, trade and forecasting. "Planned" here means
economically useful, ecologically and socially responsible activities.[2]

 Resources are
all natural material systems which as such are no commodities, but the
intactness of which is a basic prerequisite for the continued existence of the
earth's chemical and physical equilibrium and, consequently, for the survival
of mankind. Resources include: the ozone balance, the CO2 balance, the
equilibrium of sea water, the tropical forest, the krill and fish population,
etc.[2]

 World resource
balances are the planned (i.e. ecologically useful and socially responsible)
handling of resources. This comprises: the explanation, evaluation, risk
assessment and forecasting regarding world resources.[2]

Current research emphasis [2]  international raw material balances

 supply
problems of the industrial countries

 location
disadvantages of the developing countries

 dumping
problems in international raw material trade

 recycling as a
source for raw materials

 raw material
deposits and connected environmental problems in east Siberia (addendum 1)

 structural
questions and environmental problems of the Polish energy and metal economy[2]
I. Trade intermediates and natural resources

Once international trade in more than final consumer
goods is allowed, basic notions of comparative advantage need to be
re-examined. We have already discussed the limitations in a multi-commodity
word of comparing autarky prices in two countries to predict item-by-item the
pattern of trade; generally only correlations can be made except under
additional assumptions. With trade in intermediates allowed, the problems in
predicting trade in final goods became even greater. As MakKenzie (1945)
remarked in one of his classic problem on the Ricardian model, the familiar
nineteenth century trade pattern in which Lancashire produced and  exported cotton textiles would most probably
not have been observed if England  had
had to grow its own cotton [1]
. We
shall have occasion both in this section and to revert to this theme: the
pattern of trade in final goods may not be readily deducible from the
comparison of pre-trade relative prices in these markets.[3]    
I.I Middle products (intermediates)

The phrase «middle-products» was used by Sanyal and
Jones (1982) to encompass what traditionally are referred to as intermediate
goods, goods-in-process, and natural resources which have been extracted and
prepared for trade on world markets. The core concept in their model is that of
a productive spectrum whereby, at initial stages, natural resources and raw
materials are processed and, in the final stages, goods-in-process and
intermediate products are locally assembled for national consumption.
International trade, according to this view, takes place in commodities,
somewhere in the «middle» of this productive spectrum, freeing up a nation’s
input requirements in the final stages of production from its output tradeable
middle products at earlier stages.[3]

Such a view of the role of international trade
suggests a natural division between that part of the economy which produces
commodities (middle products) for the world market (including the local
economy), called the Input Tier, and that section of the economy which makes
use of internationally traded middle products as input along with local
resources to produce none-trade goods for final consumption (the Output Tier).
Ruled out by assumption in the simple version on this model is the notion that
the «middle» stages of the productive spectrum might be «thick» in the sense
that tradeable middle products might use other tradeable middle products as
inputs. In addition, in production structure in each tier of the economy as
assumed to resemble that of the specific-factors model. Labor is mobile both
among sectors in each tier and between tiers. The balance of payments provides
an additional link between the two tiers; if the trade account is balanced, the
value of total output from the Input Tier of the economy is matched by the
value of middle products used as inputs (along with labour) in the Output
Tier.[3]

Several types of questions have been raised in the
context on this model, and of central concern in each case is the allocation of
labour between tiers and the real wage. Fore example, a transfer payment which
gives rise to a trade surplus requires labour to be reallocated to the Input
Tier  as consumption falls, and this
serves unambiguously to reduce the real wage.[3]

  If domestic
(and world) prices of trade middle products remain constant to the small
country, all non-labour inputs in the Output Tier can be aggregated, a la
Hicks, into a composite middle product input, which serves to convert the
production structure in the Output Tier from an (n+1)-factor, n-commodity
specific-factors model into a two-factors, many-commodity Heckscher-Ohlin
model.[3]

In the middle-products model Input Tier is the
existence of a world market in which middle products can be exchanged for each
other that permits such a conversion.[3]

The middle-products model allows countries and sectors
to differ in the extent to which local value must be added to transform middle
products into final commodities, 
and  much  depends 
upon  this  comparison. 
It  does   not, 
however, focus upon another question: in а  vertical production 
structure with  many stages,
which goods-in-process  or middle  products does  а country  import and  which does it  export?  Two  recent 
papers  have  tackled 
this  issue independently  and with different  models. Sanyal  (1980)
assumes  that in  each of 
two countries  а commodity is
produced in а continuum of stages, with 
different Ricardian  labor-only
input structures. Depending upon technological differences and  relative country  size, а cut-off point 
will be  determined, with  one country 
producing the  commodity from raw
material stage to some intermediate 
point, and  then exporting  this good-in-process  to 
the  other  country 
where labor  is applied  to finish 
the production process.  By  contrast, 
Dixit and  Grossman (1982)  use а 
specific-factors model, with 
one  of  the  commodities
(manufacturing)  produced in  а continuum 
of stages using capital and labor (the other sector using land and  labor) [2]
.
These  stages are arranged  such 
that,  as  goods-in-process  develop towards  the
final  stage, more labor-intensive
techniques are required.  Thus with  two countries,  the labor-abundant country will tend to specialize in later
stages of the productive spectrum[3]
.[3]

They analyze how 
endowment changes  alter the  cut-off point,  as well  as investigating
issues related to content protection.[3]
I.II Natural resources

As Chapter 8 in this volume discusses,  the normative  question of  pricing
natural resources (exhaustible or renewable) has received much attention
in  the literature of the past  decade. The 
middle-products approach 
stresses that  some activities,
the extraction of natural resources, must take place locally although
international trade then allows other countries  access to  these
resources.  Obviously, comparative
advantage changes  over time  for countries  engaged in  exporting
exhaustible resource. In  early
work  Vanek (1963)  traced through  the changing  pattern of
United States trade in natural resources, and suggested that asymmetries in
resource use and availability could account for the Leontief paradox. In а
context of multi-level trade, the costs of recourse extraction  in one 
country often depend on the availability of foreign capital. Kemp and
Ohyama (1978) have  presented  а 
simple  model  of 
North  -  South 
trade in  which South  makes use of  Northern  capital  to 
develop  its  resources 
and  exports  these resources  to the North  where  they 
are  used  to 
produce  final  commodities[4]
. They
put  their model to use in  exploring the  normative issue  of
different  degrees of  bargaining strength and ability to exploit
via export taxes and tariffs in  the
two  regions. But  the model also  stresses  the
involvement  of capital  flows in 
resource extraction.  Schmitz and
Helmberger  (1979)  argue 
strongly  for  complementarity  between  trade  in 
resources and trade in capital, а point also stressed  by Williams 
in his  1929 article.  We turn to 
consider  more  generally, now,  the interaction  between
trade  in goods  and trade in factors.[3]

Addendum 1

Siberia is Among Leaders in Raw Materials Markets[5]

Siberia's rating looks more impressive in some groups
of goods than its 7-th general placing. Split the whole flow of commercial
projects into 9 groups of goods, and for 6 of them Siberia joins the leading
three:

Timber and Paper

I      
Siberia         32.6

II      Moscow          19.1

III    
St.-Petersburg  14.2

Fuel

I      
Siberia         20.3

II     
Urals           13.2

III    
Moscow          12.3

Chemical Products

I      
Moscow          17.2

II     
Siberia         15.7

III    
St.-Petersburg  11.9

Construction Materials

I      
Moscow          22.0

II     
Siberia         14.1

III    
Urals           5.6

Transportation

I      
Moscow          23.6

II     
Siberia         12.4

III    
Volga           12.1

Metals

I      
St.-Petersburg  20.9

II     
Urals           19.6

III    
Siberia         11.7
Список литературы

«The New Polgrave a dictionary of economic» Editor:
J.Eatwell, M.Mmilgate P.Newman

Chair of Raw Material Economy and World Resource
Balances Prof. Dr.rer.nat. E. Machens (temporary appointment)

«Positive Theory of International Trade» Editor: R.W.
Jones, J.P. Neary (pages 31-37)

«The World Economy 
History & Prospect» Editor: W.W Rostow (part 52 «The Future of the
World Economy» , pages 610-618)

«Siberia is Among Leaders in Raw Materials
Markets»Editors: Alexei Alexeev, Andrey Kiselev

[1]
In Jones (1980) a two-country
Recardian model is illustrated in which one commodity requires an intermediate
input and technologies differ between countries The pattern of trade can be
reversed as a result of variations in the price of the traded
intermediate.    

[2]
Both papers cite the use of the continuum concept  in Dornbusch,  Fischer, and  Samuelson
(1977).

[3]
А limitation of both papers is the assumption that
costs (or  factor proportions)  move monotonically from lower to higher
stages of production. If not, trade may take place а1 many points  in the productive spectrum in the absence of
inhibiting transport costs.

[4]
This model is described in simplified terms by Findlay
(1979).


Не сдавайте скачаную работу преподавателю!
Данный реферат Вы можете использовать для подготовки курсовых проектов.

Поделись с друзьями, за репост + 100 мильонов к студенческой карме :

Пишем реферат самостоятельно:
! Как писать рефераты
Практические рекомендации по написанию студенческих рефератов.
! План реферата Краткий список разделов, отражающий структура и порядок работы над будующим рефератом.
! Введение реферата Вводная часть работы, в которой отражается цель и обозначается список задач.
! Заключение реферата В заключении подводятся итоги, описывается была ли достигнута поставленная цель, каковы результаты.
! Оформление рефератов Методические рекомендации по грамотному оформлению работы по ГОСТ.

Читайте также:
Виды рефератов Какими бывают рефераты по своему назначению и структуре.